A "Green" Convertible Currency

by Bernard A. Lietaer

Beginning
1. The Stamp Scrip Concept2. Commodity-Based
Currency
3. The Negative Interest Rate4. Summary: Advantages of the New Currency Concept
'Community Currencies'
article

A 'Green' Convertible Currency

Many countries of the world face a fourfold dilemma. They are experiencing unemployment, inflation, and ecological degradation, and they lack a convertible currency. They produce some raw materials for which an international market exists,but because of the burden of debt servicing and a soft currency, their dilemma yearly becomes more acute.

This article proposes a solution in the form of a new convertible currency, that I call New Currency. This comprises a combination of two familiar concepts: stamp scrip and currency backed by a basket of commodities.

Stamp scrip is a medium of exchange characterized by a small monthly "user fee" or "negative interest" charge. This fee was typically levied by requiring a small stamp to be affixed to the back of the bill each month to revalidate it. The user fee gives an incentive to the bearer not to hoard this currency. Its practical and demonstrated economic effects include strong, positive impacts on employment creation and on inflation control. It also provides structural support for ecologically sound economic growth. It has been tested and used with remarkable success in a variety of cultures and historical settings, including Western Europe as recently as the 1930s.

The second concept--a currency backed by a predetermined basket of commodities--is more familiar. An original aspect of my proposed plan is that a country's central bank would guarantee delivery of the value of the basket but would remain free to deliver it in the form of any mix of the commodities included in it. This approach provides unusual stability for the international value of the currency, while guaranteeing substantial flexibility in the way the country fulfills its commitments.

The stamp scrip concept actively promotes internal economic stability and employment growth, while the basket of commodities concept ensures immediate convertibility of the national currency and the international stability of its purchasing value. These two concepts fit together by equating the negative interest rate of the stamp scrip with the approximate costs of storing, insuring, and delivering to their respective international markets the commodities in the basket.

<<<BeginningNext section>>>

1. The Stamp Scrip Concept

The negative-interest scrip concept was originally developed during the latter part of the last century by an Argentinian businessman and economist named Silvio Gesell. The basic (and unusual) premise is that money as a medium of exchange is considered a public service good, and therefore a small user fee is levied on it. Instead of receiving interest for retaining such a currency, the bearer in fact pays interest for its use (typically at a rate of 1 to 2 percent a month). Interestingly enough, Gesell's concept of "negative-interest money" was supported by John Maynard Keynes in his General Theory. However, banking interests have rather consistently strenuously opposed it, even though banks could keep a key role in a New Currency economic system.

The primary practical effect of a negative-interest currency is a strong incentive to avoid hoarding. People prefer to spend the currency very quickly on goods or services and thereby generate a chain reaction of economic transactions that otherwise would occur much more slowly or simply not at all. This means in practice a strong and immediate creation of local employment without the need for government intervention.

Thus, negative-interest scrip can be created and used in a local setting to generate local employment and other benefits. When stamp scrip was used from 1932 to 1934 in the Austrian town of Worgl (in parallel with the official state currency), there was immediate creation of additionaI employment without the need for government intervention and without the creation of new local or public debt. The alternate currency circulated with many times the rapidity of the official Austrian currency, and there was local prosperity in the midst of national depression.

Negative-interest currency can help to push inflation down. Inflation is simply the depreciation of a currency in terms of goods. A negative-interest currency--like any commodity that has a significant storage cost--becomes automatically more valuable over time (a look at the price of future delivery of gold or copper in the financial pages compared to today's "spot" price shows that effect). In addition, in a "normal" economy, there is a substantial amount of hidden debt servicing in every purchase we make--estimates put it on average at 30 to 50 percent--which would be gradually eliminated by the introduction of negative-interest currency. The combination of the automatic appreciation of the value of the currency and the gradual reduction of the interest component from all capital-intensive goods and services, results in a powerful technique to combat inflationary tendencies.

There is an additional beneficial effect with regard to the environment. The higher the money rate of interest, the stronger is the pressure to discount the future and to place immediate gains ahead of long-term concerns. With negative-interest currency, this pressure is not only absent but even reversed, and more environment-friendly priorities automatically prevail.

During the economic depression of the 1930s, Europe saw a number of practical monetary experiments with negative-interest alternative currency. The device worked splendidly. The alternative currency (typically issued by a small city or region) had many times the rapidity of circulation of the official currency, and the anticipated employment and environmental benefits were actualized. In Worgl, for example, people spontaneously started replanting forests just to dispose of their negative-interest currency in anticipation of future cash flow to be expected from the growing trees. In every case, however, the central bank halted the experiment after a few years. The experiments were blocked not because they were unsuccessful but because they were so remarkably successful that they were perceived as threatening to centralized decision-making and the central bank's monopoly on issuing currency.

<<<Previous sectionNext section >>>

2. Commodity-Based Currency

The idea of a commodity-based currency may seem to some a step backwards to a more primitive form of exchange. But in fact, from a practical point of view, commodity-secured money (for example, gold- and silver-based money) is the only type of money that can be said to have passed the test of history in market economics. The kind of unsecured currency (bank notes and treasury notes) presently used by practically all countries has been acceptable only for about half a century, and the judgment of history regarding its soundness still remains to be written.

With a commodity-based currency, a central bank could issue a New Currency backed by a basket of from three to a dozen different commodities for which there are existing international commodity markets. For instance, 100 New Currency could be worth 0.05 ounces of gold, plus 3 ounces of silver, plus 15 pounds of copper, plus 1 barrel of oil, plus 5 pounds of wool.

This New Currency would be convertible because each of its component commodities is immediately convertible. It also offers several kinds of flexibility. The central bank would agree to deliver commodities from this basket whose value in foreign currency equals the value of that particular basket. The bank would be free to substitute certain commodities of the basket for others as long as they were also part of the basket. The bank could keep and trade its commodity inventories wherever the international market was most convenient for its own purposes--Zurich for gold, London for copper, New York for silver, and so on. Because of arbitrage between all these places, it doesn't really matter where the trades would be executed, as the final hard currency proceeds would be practically equivalent. Finally, since the commodities also have futures markets, it would be perfectly possible for the bank to settle any forward amounts in New Currency, while offsetting the risks in the futures market if it so desired.

This flexibility results in a currency with very desirable characteristics. First of all, the reserves that the country could rely on--actual reserves plus production capacity--are much larger than its current stock of hard currencies and gold. The New Currency would be automatically convertible without the need for new international agreements. Since the necessary international commodity exchanges already exist, the system could be started unilaterally, without any negotiations. Because of the diversification offered by the basket of several commodities, the currency would be much more stable than any of its components--more stable, really, than any other convertible currency in today's market.


NextTop

http://www.transaction.net/money/gc/gc01.html
zisk@well.com